January 24, 2001 Eric Rasmusen notes, erasmuse@indiana.edu Http://Php.Indiana.edu/~erasmuse 61. Harold Hotelling, ``Stability in Competition,'' Economic Journal, 39: 41-57 (March 1929). p. 347. In both the original article and the 1952 reprint in Stigler and Boulding's AEA Readings in Price Theory, there is a typo: the equations are f(q_1+q_2) + q_1 f(q_1+q_2) =0 and f(q_1+q_2) + q_2 f(q_1+q_2) =0, lacking the subscripts in the second term of each equation to indicate derivatives. p. 350. Figure 2 should have the lowest diagonal line hitting the P_1 axis at 30. In the original and in the reader, it looks like it hits at about 35. We haven't corrected that, but the 1952 reprint in Stigler and Boulding's AEA Readings in Price Theory did. p. 351. The line where dpi_1/dp_1=0 is the reaction curve for player 1. It is the line that connects RTE in Figure 2. Footnote 8. This footnote is confusing because it redraws Figure 2 in words, and so looking at Figure 2 to understand it is not very helpful. Hotelling ought to have given us a fresh figure to illustrate this case. He is talking about the situation where the two firms are located too close to each other for the equations he just described to be applicable. In his example here, l=20, a=11, b=8, and c=1. Then, the two boundary lines for solutions are p_1-p_2 = (+_) (1)(20-11-8) = (+_)1, which means that the two firms' prices cannot differ by more than 1, or one firm will get all the other's customers, and, in fact, get the entire line of length 20. The calculus method used in the paper was valid only under the assumption that the firms each held onto their own extreme customers and split the ones in between them. In the example, the calculus solutions yield p_1 = (1) (20+ (11-8)/3)) = 21 and p_2 = (1) (20- (11-8)/3)) = 19. That is a difference of 2, not 1, so all of the customers would prefer Firm 2. The essential problem is that when the firms are located close together, the model is a lot closer to pure, undifferentiated Bertrand competition. If a=b, for example, so the firms were on top of each other, it is clear that Hotelling's price equations wouldn't work, but they would yield definite numbers nonetheless-- identical prices of 20 if l=20, c=1, and a=b, for example. Hotelling seems to have noticed this kind of problem when he thought about optimal location of an entrant-- see footnote 9 on page 354. Do not trust his supposed solution in footnotes 8 and 9. p. 354. Hotelling suggests that someone setting up a subdivision, a new tract of homes and businesses, would want to locate two businesses so as to maximize the businesses's profits, which would allow him to sell the land to those businesses at higher prices. He does not note that so doing reduces the value of the homes in the subdivision even more, because the businesses' price gains are the homeowners' losses, plus the homeowners would have higher transportation costs if the business locations were inefficient.